Could climate change have come at worse time for UK coastal dwellers?
Many years ago my then girlfriend told me that she found it hard to respect me because I lived in ‘rented accommodation’. I remember at the time thinking what a curiously formal description it was (you can imagine Wallace using it when speaking to Grommit), and what a deadly weight it seemed to have. Looking back, two things strike me. First is my naivety in not seeing this as a signal that the relationship might struggle, and second is the place of housing tenure in considering loss of homes due to the impacts of climate change and associated government policy.
I
was reminded of this a couple of weeks ago when the story about the
availability of insurance for those in areas with a high risk of flooding was
covered by the Guardian[1]. Predictably, the subsequent on-line
discussion prompted a range of views, one of which I would suggest is broadly
represented by the (verbatim) post: “Why should I bail out…some idiot who buys a house in
a flood risk area?”. Broadening the area under discussion to cover
responsibility for adaptation to climate change as it applies to coastal
dwellers rather than simply flooding, there is an important point to be
considered here.
As things stand, those who have been told
that they can expect their homes to be lost to the sea at some point can also
expect to bear the full cost. Our Guardian commentator would presumably see
this as proper given the individuals’ presumed choice to have bought houses is
such locations. But this is to ignore an opportunity to put such questions into
a wider and more interesting context with regard to the allocation of risks.
The Anglo-Saxon model
The UK pursues a distinctive approach
to housing tenure that favours owner-occupation – characterised by Ronald[2] as
the ‘Anglo-Saxon’ model. This has not always been the case, however. He
explains that “At
the beginning of the 20th century most British households rented
their homes from private landlords and as few as one in ten were
owner-occupiers”, and that despite the promise of state support for local
authorities in providing new houses for rent in the early 1920s “funds were
increasingly shifted…into the provision of owner-occupied homes” (p.22). By
1938 the proportion of owner occupied housing had increased to 32 per cent.
The
immediate post-war period and the Labour government’s welfare state, Ronald
tells us, “called for radical changes in housing policy
which involved the mass building of rental housing” (p.23). However, this was
followed by a reversal in policy which appears to have proceeded more or less
uninterrupted ever since. In the 1950s the Conservatives “committed themselves
to the ideal of the ‘property owning democracy’” (23) with homeownership
establishing itself as the majority tenure by the 1970s. The accompanying property
price-boom not only established an “enduring belief that homeownership is one
of the best, if not the best, investment accessible to ordinary people” but
also saw Labour governments become “more partisan to homeownership policy…”.
(23)
Under
the Thatcher government, housing privatisation – including the sale of council
houses - became a focus of policy accompanied, Ronald observes, by deregulation
of the credit market so that by the end of 1990s “the homeownership rate was
above 64 per cent” (p.23). Despite an initially cautious approach, Ronald
explains that “…New Labour soon began to warm-up to owner-occupation”. In 2005 plans to “extend homeownership to 75
percent of housing” were announced, with Brown during his tenure as Prime Minister
“explicit about his desire to further expand opportunities for homeownership
and enhance the features of an asset-based social security system.” (p.24) Thus, we might observe that the
individual’s assumption of risk through home ownership can at least in part be
historically located and be identified as the product of a politically
consensual policy transformation – with this style of tenure operating in
lockstep with emerging orthodoxies concerning individualism, welfare and
citizenship.
The General Strike 1926 - crossing London Bridge |
Finally,
Ronald identifies the current era as “a period of ‘total homeownership policy’
whereby this type of tenure is “almost universally considered the ‘best’ or
‘natural’ way to produce and consume housing” (30). ‘Tenure imperialism’, he
calls it.
Where
the heart is
Writing some years previously, Gurney[3]
explores the ways in which the idea of ‘home’ – being ‘where the heart is’ and
‘where charity begins’, and ‘an Englishman’s castle’, is closely associated
with owner-occupation in government policy. He observes of policy documents that:
“’Home’ is
frequently used to differentiate between the dwellings of householders in owner
occupation and in rented accommodation; and dwellings of those in owner
occupation are imbued with the warmth and security ‘home’ whilst renters are
accorded a more Spartan language to describe their dwelling.” (p.172) In the
1995 Housing White paper, Gurney argues, the idea of ‘home’ exists in a much
more meaningful way for those in home ownership than it does for renters, and
is expressed through “ideas of love, warmth, comfort, pride, independence and
self-respect” (p.173).
Policy
papers also associate home ownership with the uptake and expression of certain values.
A 1971 Department of the Environment and Welsh Office command paper sees the
government associate home ownership with social advance, whilst in 1981 the
Department of the Environment has it that home ownership “ensures the spread of
wealth through society…enables parents to accrue wealth for their children and
stimulates the attitudes of independence and self-reliance that are the bedrock
of a free society” This, proposes Gurney, “carries with it the expectation of
home owners being good citizens, good parents and good caretakers.” (176) Perhaps
even more fundamentally, Gurney tells us, the 1971 Department of the
Environment and Welsh Office command paper tells us that the desire for home
ownership is a “basic and natural desire” (p.178), with the obverse presumably
the case for those living under other tenancy arrangements.
I’m
not sure how familiar my old girlfriend was with government housing policy
papers - not very, is my guess. However, is hard not to wonder at the power of official
pronouncement to shape individuals’ opinions and actions through various means.
And
I would challenge the individual who responded in such glib fashion to the
story in the Guardian to reconsider his (or her) position on the
individualisation of risk. I would never argue that those of who own homes on
the coast that are at risk from rising sea levels have not exercised choice in
so doing. But it is clearly the case that the situation we find ourselves in is
significantly the result of forces associated with political preference and the
cultivation of certain values, and that accordingly we are threatened as much
by socio-economic and political impacts as we are natural ones.
Had
climate change as currently understood become an issue in the same way 100
years ago, the consequences for coastal dwellers might have looked very
different. Far fewer would have owned
their homes and been exposed to the kinds of risks identified here. Had it
happened before the 1970s housing boom then the amount of capital at stake for those
who did own their homes would have been smaller relative to earnings, and a
state welfare may have been better placed to supported losers. It is also well
documented that sea defence in the UK was provided more on the basis of
vulnerability in the UK until relatively recently. This is, of course, to
simplify. However…
With
best wishes
Chris
[1] http://www.guardian.co.uk/money/2012/mar/07/flood-hit-homeowners-invest-defence
[2] Ronald, R. 2008.
Market-Liberal Homeowner Societies: Questions of Convergance in & around an
Anglo-Saxon model? Housing Finance International, March 2008, pp. 21-34.
[3] Gurney,
C. 1999. Pride and Prejudice: Discourses of Normalisation in Public and
Private Accounts of Home Ownership.
Journal of Housing Studies, Vol. 14. No. 2, 163-183.